Having said all that. there some serious flaws in the proposed AV system and I wish to focus here on one of them.....
Most critiques of AV focus on its main drawback, which is that it is not a proportional system. There is no guarantee that it will not produce barmy national results (such as the party with fewer votes winning the national election) just as the current FPTP system sometimes does (twice in my own short lifetime!).
I've constructed an highly contrived but simple example which shows one way in which AV can go wrong even within a single constituency:
Let us assume we have a very small constituency with 9 voters and 3 candidates: the usual Labour, LibDem, and Tory. Let us further assume that the preferences of these 9 voters are as follows:
* | Lib | Lab | Con |
voter1 | 1 | 3 | 2 |
voter2 | 1 | 3 | 2 |
voter3 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
voter4 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
voter5 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
voter6 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
voter7 | 2 | 3 | 1 |
voter8 | 2 | 3 | 1 |
voter9 | 2 | 3 | 1 |
Where "1" = first choice, "2" = second choice, and "3 .... okay you get the idea. ;-)
The problem with the current system (FPTP) is clear: Labour wins with 44% of first preferences even though the other 56% didn't have Labour as their first choice and both the Labour and Conservative voters could clearly live with a Liberal victory.
So what does AV give us?
There would need to be 2 rounds:
In the first round, the results would be: Labour 44%, Lib 22%, and Con 33%. Since the LibDems come out last, they would be eliminated and the second preferences of those who voted for the unsuccessful LibDem candidate would be taken into account. This would give final totals of: Lab 44% and Con 56% - a Conservative victory.
This is a rather unsatisfactory result since, just looking at the figures in the above table, I think most fair minded people would conclude that the Liberal candidate was the best compromise given the range of preferences expressed.
The problem here, with the straight AV system, is that it gives second (and lower) preferences (once they are counted) the same weight as first preferences. Straight AV also ignores the second preferences of those who vote for the most successful candidate in the first round.
Why not simply weight each preference (in the counting system behind the scenes I mean - I'm not advocating a more complicated voting system)?
If a first choice got 3 points, a second choice got 2 points and a third choice got 1 point, the results in the above table would give: Lib 37%, Lab 31%, Con 31%. A LibDem victory.
This would be almost as easy to count as FPTP (only a single round required) and (in this example at least) produces a result which accords with our intuitions of "fairness" and the "best compromise".
I have made this example as small as possible and chosen the figures carefully to illustrate the point, but the example is not particularly far-fetched and could (in its fundamental features)easily be repeated in a real election on a larger scale.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments are moderated, but you can leave them without registering.